It is not likely that communications policy reform will be a
hot campaign issue during this election cycle. After all, spurring job creation
and investment, growing the economy, increasing productivity, and reducing the
nation's debt and deficit are likely to be the "macro" topics that
dominate the campaigns – and well they should be.
You probably won't find the candidates, whether President
Obama or Mitt Romney, or candidates for Senate and House seats, arguing about
how to address the spectrum crunch, or implement reform of the universal
service fund, or eliminate outdated video rules, or resolve the decade-old "special
access" proceeding.
I get this. I am not suggesting that these often seemingly
esoteric communications policy issues should become standard run-of-the-mill
campaign fodder.
But I do want to suggest that, with the communications,
information, and entertainment market sectors comprising fully one-sixth of the
nation's economy, communications policy matters. More pointedly, the right communications
policies can spur job creation and investment, help grow the economy, and
increase productivity. The wrong policies can have the opposite effect.
What I want to do here is just offer some reformist positions
– you might even say "talking points" – that would be worthy of
consideration and debate if
candidates were trying to integrate communications policy reform into a broader
discussion concerning an overall program for spurring economic growth and new
investment. Even if they are not campaign issues, these proposals should be on
the table for consideration as policymakers contemplate communications policy
reform.
In my view, each of these proposals, if adopted, would be a
net positive for the economy, certainly on a long-term basis, even if not
necessarily on a "next quarter" basis.
1. Congress
should adopt a new Digital Age Communications Act which eliminates the current
regulatory "stovepipes" grounded in no longer relevant
techno-functional characteristics, and the new statute should replace the
public interest standard with an antitrust-like competition standard that
places consumer welfare, not competitor welfare, at the forefront.
Rationale:
We need a new communications law that does not regulate services differentially
based on the technologies employed and which requires a convincing showing of
market failure and consumer harm before regulating. The Digital Age Communications Act introduced in the Senate in December 2005 by
Sen. Jim DeMint remains a good model for a market-oriented statutory framework
that would reduce unnecessary regulation.
2. Eliminate
the current dual review of communications mergers and acquisitions by the
Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission on the one hand, and the FCC on
the other, so that the antitrust authorities assess the competitive impacts of
the transactions, and the FCC assesses whether, if the transaction is approved,
the parties will be in compliance with all existing laws and regulations.
Rationale:
Now, in an era of large budget deficits, there is substantial overlap in the
work done by the antitrust authorities and the FCC, with the duplication
leading to unnecessary expenditure of substantial government and private sector
resources and delays in the review process. And FCC transaction reviews under
the vague public interest standard invite arbitrary and unpredictable agency decisionmaking,
along with the now standard bargaining over so-called "voluntary"
concessions that epitomizes "regulation by condition." I first wrote
about this in 2000 in a piece titled, "Any Volunteers?" The current process discourages companies
from engaging in transactions that may increase efficiency and productivity.
3. Develop
a national policy framework that makes it more difficult for localities and
states to slow down the build-out of wireless infrastructure necessary to
accommodate surging consumer demand.
Rationale:
There are various measures that must be taken to address the spectrum crunch, such
as allowing the secondary spectrum market to function more freely. But one
helpful measure would be the development of some form of national policy that
has the effect of accelerating local and state processes for siting towers and
issuing permits for new infrastructure build-outs. Capital investment would
flow more quickly than at present.
4. Accelerate
meaningful reform of the universal service subsidy regime and transition, over
time, to a more limited program primarily directed to providing subsidy support
to eligible low-income persons, not to high-cost communications providers.
Rationale:
Until the FCC's high-cost universal service subsidy fund is further reformed, and
as the FCC gets bogged down in interminable proceedings developing new
"high cost" models and considering waivers from its newly adopted
rules, wasteful disbursements of subsidies supporting inefficient telephone
providers will continue. This discourages investment in new, more efficient
telecom network infrastructure. Absent further reform and resolve, the USF
subsidy program is a "telecom Solyndra" waiting to happen. Consider
this example: In a recent meeting between the Secretary of Agriculture and the Administrator of the
Rural Utilities Service and the FCC Chairman, the Secretary suggested the standard
for relief from a reduction of subsidies to rural telephone companies "should
be tied to a default on an obligation to government, not to loss of voice
service." In other words, regardless of whether continued subsidies are
necessary to fulfill their intended purpose of making available communications
services, subsidies should continue to flow to keep government loans from going
bad. This ill-conceived Solyndra-like policy would be bad for consumers who
must pay for the subsidies through USF surcharges on their telephone bills, and
who, by the way, are taxpayers too.
5. Eliminate
outdated legacy video regulations, such as must-carry, leased access, program
access, program carriage mandates, and media ownership restrictions.
Rationale:
These various regulations were put in place in the analog-era during a time
when the video marketplace still retained some monopoly characteristics. In
today's digital broadband video marketplace, competition among various video
providers using cable, satellite, fiber, telephone, wireless, and Internet
platforms is fierce, so the regulations are no longer necessary. And with the
government dictating categories of programming that must be carried and under
what terms, and the amount of communications capacity that must be set-aside by
providers for use by others, the regulations not only discourage investment,
they offend free speech principles to boot.
6. Sunset
all FCC rules every seven years, subject to retention if the agency makes a
showing of a compelling justification for keeping the regulation.
Rationale:
Historically, the FCC, often by its own admission, has been notably slow in
eliminating regulations from its books that no longer serve any purpose. Now,
even the Obama Administration, through its Executive Order, is urging agencies to engage in retrospective reviews to get rid of,
or relax, outdated regulatory requirements. The periodic regulatory review
provisions in the Telecom Act of 1996 did not accomplish the stated purpose of
eliminating outdated regulations. With marketplace changes continuing at a
rapid pace, driven by the development of new technologies, a large number of
FCC regulations, however well-intentioned, become obsolete over time.
Therefore, all agency regulations should "sunset" seven years after
adoption, unless the FCC, after providing an opportunity for public notice and
comment, finds there is a compelling justification for retaining the rule.
I know there are other good proposals that could be offered
as well, and I certainly know that readers will not agree with all of these.
So, as always, your reactions are welcome.