skip to main |
skip to sidebar
On March 30, I published a blog entitled "A
Truly Free Market TV Marketplace." The piece essentially made two fundamental
points in response to a letter
from the American Conservative Union asserting that the current retransmission
regime represents a "functioning market" for bargaining over the
rights for carriage of video programming.
First, I said: "[I]n light of all the various legacy
laws and regulations that together overlay the video marketplace – must carry,
network non-duplication and syndicated exclusivity, compulsory licensing, and
others -- the retransmission regime operates in the overall context of an
'unfree' market."
And the second point I made was this: "Because I know a free market when I see one,
I commend Senator DeMint and Rep. Scalise for introducing the 'Next Generation
Television Marketplace Act.' The bill certainly represents the direction in
which policy needs to go."
A few days ago, the Competitive Enterprise Institute's Ryan
Radia published a long and thoughtful blog entitled "A
Free Market Defense of Retransmission Consent." In it, Ryan responds
to my piece and to a similar one by my friend, Adam Thierer. Adam's essay is
entitled "Towards
a True Free Market in Television."
I don't want to repeat here, on a Friday afternoon no less,
all the substance of the three pieces. If you haven't read them, and if you are interested in the debate about the current
retransmission consent regime and the issues surrounding the "Next Generation
Television Marketplace Act" bill introduced by Sen. DeMint and Rep.
Scalise, you should read the pieces as background for what follows.
Here I want to respond to Ryan's post by making just a few
points. They show that, in reality, he essentially agrees with much of what I
say (and Adam Thierer as well.)
Before addressing the substantive points, it would be an
exhibition of false modesty if I didn't acknowledge that I appreciate Ryan
calling my piece "superb" and calling me "venerable." And,
best of all, a "free market policy icon." Thanks, Ryan, for the kind
words.
So, on to the two essential points.
Ryan
states that he wholeheartedly agrees with me "that ACU’s characterization
of the current regime as a 'functioning market' is inaccurate." This
is a very fundamental point to acknowledge in any discussion of the current
retransmission regime.
And he agrees with me that "[i]t’s high time for Congress to liberalize the
television marketplace to bring it into the 21st century. Sen. DeMint and Rep.
Scalise’s bill would, if enacted, mark a major step toward a freer video
market." I appreciate acknowledgement of this point as well. Recall I
concluded my blog by stating the DeMint-Scalise bill "represents the
direction in which policy needs to go." I didn't say the bill was perfect
in every respect. Few bills are, at least as introduced.
At
bottom, though, Ryan concludes that the bill "could be improved by leaving
retransmission consent intact." In between his acknowledgment that the
current retransmission consent regime is not a "functioning market"
and his acknowledgement that the DeMint-Scalise bill constitutes a "major
step" forward, he goes through a lengthy and useful exposition of the
major regulatory overlays in today's video marketplace.
The sheer length of the exposition pretty much proves the
point concerning the extent to which the current video marketplace is burdened
with a real mish-mash of protectionist-inspired legacy regulation which is
ill-suited for today's competitive video marketplace. Ryan himself seems to
agree that the must carry, network non-duplication, and syndicated exclusivity
regulations which confer upon broadcasters certain statutory protectionist privileges
should be repealed. And I think he would say the same with respect to the protectionist
compulsory license benefitting cable operators.
Out of the current regime, the only regulation that Ryan
suggests possibly should remain on the books is retransmission consent, albeit
in an altered form so that the FCC's role in supervision and enforcement is
eliminated in favor of a judicial private right of action. He recognizes that,
for the vast majority of video programming, it is not necessary to preserve
retransmission consent in order to ensure program owners are compensated, by
virtue of a private bargaining process, by pay-TV providers. Pay-TV providers
would have to negotiate for the right to carry copyrighted programming with the
rights holders, whether they are local broadcasters, national or regional networks,
syndicators, or whomever.
In the end, when you cut through it all, Ryan is concerned
that if the DeMint-Scalise bill were adopted as is, local broadcasters
"would hold far fewer cards, losing the regulations that benefit
them." He acknowledges that the "disintermediation of broadcasters
might benefit consumers, especially if it translates into lower fees (and,
hence, more content choices and/or lower television bills.") This is no
small acknowledgement.
But Ryan worries that deregulation possibly may have a
"dark side." Without a statutory retransmission consent requirement
in place, pay-TV operators may be able to free ride on whatever
"incremental value" local broadcasters provide through certain signal
enhancements such as display tickers ("crawlers") with sports scores,
school closings, election results, and the like. Ryan focuses on this possible
"incremental value" of local broadcasters' signals because he acknowledges
that almost all their programming is, in fact, copyrighted. Thus, the vast
majority of local broadcasters' programming would be subject to private
bargaining between the rights holders and pay-TV providers before it could be
carried by pay-TV providers.
Ryan acknowledges that the economic value of the local
broadcasters' signal enhancements beyond copyrighted programming (and whatever else
is left that is not subject to "fair use") is unknown. He suggests
that if the signal enhancements have any incremental economic value at all, pay-TV
operators' carriage of such signals without negotiated compensation offends the
long-standing common law equitable principle of unjust enrichment, which holds
that a person who is unjustly enriched at the expense of another is entitled to
restitution.
Now the whole notion that local broadcasters are entitled to
compensation for the mere retransmission of their local signals is somewhat questionable
in any event, because the signals can be picked up for free by anyone within
reception range. Ryan acknowledges this was the law prior to 1992 when Congress
created the current must-carry/retransmission statutory regime. I think this is
an important point.
But putting this point aside for the moment, my sense is
that it likely would be preferable to have in place the deregulated marketplace
envisioned by the DeMint-Scalise bill than to retain, as the last standing
relic of the current regime, a statutory retransmission consent requirement. If there is any justification for compensation for mere retransmission at all, which I don't concede, perhaps it would be preferable to leave the matter of compensation for a pay-TV operator's
carriage of a local signal to the courts under the common law theories of
unjust enrichment. I doubt if the "incremental value" derived from
crawlers and such would amount to much enrichment in the real world
marketplace.
Ryan's contribution to the debate is welcome. To my mind,
his acknowledgement that the current retransmission consent regime does not
constitute a functioning market and his acknowledgement that the DeMint-Scalise
bill represents a major step forward are both significant and important. As I
head into the weekend, I am happy to emphasize those key elements of agreement,
rather than exaggerate the differences that exist.